My
story begins on December 8, when the P-G
published Molly Rush's letter advocating single payer health care.
This was followed on December 16 by a reply from Jim Roth—a
pharmaceutical salesperson(!)—implying that single-payer is too
costly and denies health care to some citizens. If you're going to
continue, you should stop and read Mr. Roth's letter.
The next day, I
wrote the following:
Mr. Roth notes
that all countries with single-payer finance it with a value added
tax. However, the type of tax used to fund health care is
irrelevant. The important point is that single payer costs those
countries considerably less than our complex system of public and
private insurance. According to a 2013 report of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), the US currently
spends on average $8,508 per person each year on health care,
compared to an OECD average of $3,322. Yet the US is 26th
out of 40 OECD countries in life expectancy. The amount Americans
spend on health care due to the combined burden of taxes, insurance
and out-of-pocket costs would be greatly reduced under single-payer.
Mr. Roth claims
that people in single-payer countries have longer wait times for
elective surgery and are sometimes denied such care. This depends on
the country and what you consider “elective surgery.” US
insurance companies also refuse to cover some elective procedures.
However, if these were serious problems, you would expect residents
of single-payer countries to be dissatisfied with their country's
health care system. A 2013 survey by the Commonwealth Fund compared
consumer satisfaction in the US to nine European countries and
Canada, all with single-payer. Americans were by far the most
dissatisfied,with 75% saying the system needs fundamental changes or
should be completely rebuilt.
Finally, Mr.
Roth suggests that we could lower health insurance costs by allowing
it to be sold across state lines. It is true that if some states
were to deregulate health insurance and if residents of any state
were allowed to buy that product, premiums might come down. But
those people would be buying insurance with little value should they
become seriously ill. The Affordable Care Act is intended to prevent
exploitation of consumers by establishing a baseline definition of
adequate health insurance.
Of course, the
primary purpose of single-payer is not just to save money, but to
save the lives of some of the millions of Americans who are currently
uninsured.
On
December 29, the P-G published
two replies to Mr. Roth. Both offered primarily anecdotal evidence
suggesting that at least one family—the author's—had lived in a
single-payer country and was satisfied with their health care system.
The main difference between them is that the first referred to the
British system and the second the Dutch. While both were
well-written and persuasive, I thought they were redundant, and might
have been better supplemented by my data referring to larger numbers
of people and countries.
It's possible my
letter was rejected because it is poorly written or exceeds their
250-word limit. However, Mr. Roth's letter, at 318 words, also
breaks this rule, as do many others they publish. They could easily
have edited my letter. Clearly, exceeding the word limit was a mistake. In
retrospect, I should have dropped the third paragraph.
My hypothesis,
based on this and other previous experiences, is that my letter was
rejected because it contained too much data. Imagine an experiment
in which parallel letters to the editor are sent to a random sample
of newspapers. Both letters would make exactly the same points, but
one would support each point with research, while the other would
support them with anecdotes or merely claim that these were the
author's personal opinions. My guess is that fewer of the
data-driven letters would be published.
I have
two possible, though somewhat inconsistent, explanations for my
hypothesis. The first assumes that the editors wanted to present the
single payer argument sympathetically. It's based on a common cognitive error known as the base-rate fallacy.
People find anecdotal evidence more persuasive that statistical base
rates, even though the base rates summarize data from larger, more
representative samples. The people who made the decision may have found the two letters they published to be more persuasive
than mine.
My
second explanation makes the reasonable assumption that the
gatekeepers at the P-G are
opposed to single-payer. If so, they may assume that my inclusion of
data makes the letter too
persuasive. That is, they may be willing to acknowledge that there
are some Pittsburghers who favor single-payer, but it may be
unrealistic to expect them to publish statistics suggesting that the
arguments of single-payer advocates are factually correct.
I hope I'm wrong.
I really want to encourage the use of research evidence to change the
health care system, and society in general, for the better. If this
strategy is counterproductive, that's genuinely disturbing.
You may also be interested in reading:
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments are always welcome.